Tax Notes logo

Pillar 2 as a De Facto New Revenue Allocation Mechanism

Posted on Oct. 2, 2023
Takayuki Nagato
Takayuki Nagato

Takayuki Nagato is a professor of law at Gakushuin University in Japan. The author thanks Allison Christians for valuable comments on the preliminary draft.

The research for this article was partly conducted during the author’s stay at the New York University School of Law as a Hauser Global Research Fellow in 2019-2020. This research was supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number JP18K12634 and JP22K01162.

In this article, Nagato argues that the OECD’s pillar 2 is a de facto new mechanism for allocating taxing rights on the deemed excess returns of the largest multinational enterprises, and that pillar 2 without pillar 1 would unjustifiably provide low-tax investment hubs, inaccurately classified as “source” jurisdictions under transfer pricing rules with the opportunity to maintain a relatively competitive tax environment while raising additional tax revenue from international cooperation to set a corporate tax competition floor.

I. Introduction

Following the OECD/G-20 inclusive framework’s October 2021 agreement on a two-pillar solution within the base erosion and profit-shifting project,1 BEPS 2.0 has entered its implementation phase. According to the conventional narrative, BEPS 2.0 pillar 1 intends to reallocate taxing rights between source and residence jurisdictions to “address the tax challenges arising from the digitalisation of the economy.” Pillar 2 intends to address the remaining BEPS issues.2

However even after the 2021 agreement, the likelihood of pillar 1 producing a multilateral tax convention remains questionable because of the expected lack of participation by the United States. U.S. ratification of the multilateral convention is expected to be a challenge because of the U.S. Senate’s negative attitude toward it.3 In contrast, pillar 2 is more feasible because it is implemented unilaterally through domestic legislation. There is already a series of national legislative movements in important jurisdictions, with the exception of the United States, to implement pillar 2.4

This study challenges the stated purposes of the two pillars. Each pillar creates allocation rules for taxing the returns deemed excessive of the largest multinational enterprises.5 The debate over pillar 2’s ordering priority rules reflects conflict among jurisdictions over taxing rights on deemed excess returns, undertaxed to date. Nevertheless, the project aims to avoid tampering with the traditional allocation of taxing rights.

The study also attempts to challenge the conventional academic narrative on the power balance between jurisdictions in the international tax policymaking arena. The literature focuses on the unfair relationship between developed and developing countries. This study not only focuses on this relationship, but also sheds light on the relationship between small and large developed countries. I argue that international cooperation on pillar 2 without implementing pillar 1 would unjustifiably provide low-tax investment hubs, inaccurately classified as source jurisdictions under today’s problematic transfer pricing rules, with the opportunity to maintain a relatively competitive tax environment while raising additional tax revenue from international cooperation to set a corporate tax competition floor.

To achieve this study’s goals, I will look back on the development of the two-pillar solution, from the BEPS action 1 final report published in October 2015 to the publication of administrative guidance in July.6 This study separates the development into three periods:

  • before the Biden administration;

  • from the start of the Biden administration until the inclusive framework agreement in October 2021; and

  • after the 2021 agreement.

This classification reveals which group of jurisdictions is expected to enjoy favorable treatment in pillar 2.

The remainder of this article is organized as follows:

  • Section II chronologically summarizes the development of the two-pillar solution, focusing on the distributive aspects among jurisdictions;

  • Section III analyzes who will benefit from the GLOBE model rules and the administrative guidance to reveal that investment hubs are the winners of the deal, notwithstanding the continued criticism that pillar 2 will be the most favorable to the largest developed countries, home to many MNEs; and

  • Section IV concludes.

II. Development of the Two-Pillar Solution

A. Before the Biden Administration

1. The Genesis of the Reallocation of Taxing Rights

The original BEPS project was not intended to change the framework for allocating taxing rights, which originated in the 1920s.7 This is despite the fact that from the beginning of the project the question of whether BEPS problems can be solved without getting into the more fundamental question of the appropriate allocation of tax bases had been raised.8

The Task Force on the Digital Economy did not make a specific recommendation to introduce a new tax nexus of significant economic presence for the digital economy in the BEPS action 1 final report published October 2015.9 Rather, it highlighted the difficulty of ring-fencing the digital economy for tax purposes.10 At the same time, it was agreed that the task force would continue its work on taxation of the digital economy to report by 2020.11 BEPS 1.0 did not bring stability into the landscape of taxation of large MNEs partly because it did not prohibit countries from taking unilateral measures, provided they respected existing treaty obligations.12

Countries’ unilateral measures include the diverted profits tax in the United Kingdom, the multinational antiavoidance law, the diverted profits tax in Australia, and the equalization levy in India. In September 2017 the European Commission proposed taking collective action at the EU level to achieve fair taxation of large digital companies.13 This is important in terms of not only developing countries but also developed countries in the EU calling for reconsideration of the allocation of taxing rights, although the European Commission’s solution was intended to be confined to the digital economy.14 In March 2018 the European Commission proposed two directives, both of which were not enacted because of a failure to obtain a unanimous consensus. One is a proposal for a council directive to establish a taxable nexus for digital businesses as a long-term solution,15 and the other is a proposal for a council directive to introduce common digital services taxes in the EU single market as a short-term interim solution.16 While the European DSTs proposal was finally abandoned in March 2019,17 several EU member countries, including France, the United Kingdom, Spain, and Italy, unilaterally enacted national DSTs.

The OECD’s 2018 interim report, “Tax Challenges Arising From Digitalisation,” classifies inclusive framework members into three groups.18 The first sees a misalignment between the place of value creation and the place of taxation. It is limited to highly digitalized business models relying on user participation. This group believes that the need to reconsider the allocation of taxing rights is limited to digital businesses while supporting the existing allocation of taxing rights for other businesses.

In contrast, the second group sees the digitalization of the economy as posing a challenge to the effectiveness of the existing international taxation framework and looks to reconsider the criteria for allocating taxing rights more generally, not only for digitalized business models.

The third group finds that the BEPS action plan largely addresses double nontaxation, and does not need to reconsider the framework of international tax rules. Under this grouping, the EU’s major powers, as the first group of countries, have shown their support for reconsidering, even though it was limited to digital businesses, the allocation of taxing rights, leading to pillar 1.

2. The Genesis of the Global Minimum Taxation

The idea of global minimum taxation in pillar 2 originated from the declared positions of Germany and France on the minimum taxation of profits in the Common Corporate Tax Base Directive.19 The two countries proposed the idea of global minimum taxation at the G-7 meeting in June 2018. This new proposal was supported by the G-7 countries, except for the United Kingdom.20 The United States welcomed the proposal because it had already introduced the global intangible low-taxed income rules and the base erosion and antiabuse tax rules in the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act.21 Then, at the urging of Germany and France,22 the idea of a global minimum tax was introduced to the G-20 in December 2018. Pascal Saint-Amans, then-director of the OECD Centre for Tax Policy and Administration, thought it was difficult to connect this to the OECD mandate of addressing tax challenges from the digitalization of the economy.23 The result was a distinct new topic for the international tax reform project approved by the inclusive framework in January 2019.24

3. Linkage of Two Pillars

The policy note published in January 2019 was the first public announcement of the two-pillar solution;25 and the Programme of Work, published in May 2019 after the public consultation26 process, detailed the architecture of the international tax reform plan.27 It was explained that pillar 1 “addresses the broader challenges of the digitalised economy and focuses on the allocation of taxing rights,” and pillar 2 “addresses remaining BEPS issues.”28 The proposal in pillar 2 was named the global anti-base-erosion (GLOBE) proposal.29

The Programme of Work detailed three proposals under pillar 1:

  • the user participation proposal;

  • the marketing intangibles proposal; and

  • the significant economic presence proposal.30

The user participation proposal was suggested by the United Kingdom. The U.K. strategy is to extend its taxing rights against U.S. digital companies while resisting a reform proposal to allow a more general move toward destination-based taxation via the value creation principle in the BEPS project.31

The marketing intangibles proposal was from the United States to avoid ring-fencing digital businesses. It was epoch-making for the United States to propose a plan to reallocate taxing rights rather than just resist the wave of DSTs in other countries.32

The significant economic presence proposal came from India and was supported by other developing countries whose influence in reforming the international tax regime is increasing in the G-20 and the inclusive framework.33

Even though pillar 1 was revolutionary because its objective was to reconsider the allocation of taxing rights, the two-pillar solution was soon criticized as a diversion from the BEPS action 1 final and interim reports’ focus on expanding source taxation, to protecting residence taxation in pillar 2. The leap was seen as influenced by the richest developed OECD countries.34

The OECD secretariat developed a unified approach under pillar 1 by reconciling three separate ideas. The secretariat then proposed it for public consultation in October 2019.35 The unified approach:

  • covers highly digital business models but goes wider — broadly focusing on consumer-facing businesses;

  • creates a new nexus, not dependent on physical presence but largely based on sales;

  • uses a new profit allocation rule that goes beyond the arm’s-length principal; and

  • increases tax certainty.36

Under the unified approach, a share of deemed residual profit (amount A) will be allocated to market jurisdictions as a new taxing right. According to the preliminary findings of an economic impact assessment:

on average, low and middle-income economies would gain from pillar 1, experiencing a higher rate of increase in revenues than high-income economies even though, larger market jurisdictions will benefit more in absolute.37

On the other hand:

Investment hubs, where the analysis suggests that levels of residual profit are high, would experience significant losses in tax base.38

Small European countries, including Ireland, were therefore dissatisfied with the unified approach,39 even though they did not officially express opposition.40

The unified approach had inherent difficulties from the outset: It would require a revision of tax treaties; and it was unlikely to find support among more than two-thirds of the U.S. Senate, even though Steven Mnuchin, the Trump administration Treasury secretary, was supportive. Just before the G-20 meeting in December 2019, the United States announced that it supported the unified approach as a “safe harbor,” optional for corporations, while it fully supports a pillar 2 solution.41

The U.S. safe harbor proposal raised doubts about the feasibility of pillar 1. There was fear that the process might increase tax revenue of large residence countries through pillar 2 without pillar 1 augmenting it for source developing countries.42 Concern was heightened by a June 12, 2020, letter from Mnuchin to the finance ministers of several European countries that already had DSTs. The letter suggested delaying work on pillar 1 until the end of 2020 because of the COVID-19 pandemic. It added that the United States would welcome continuation of work on pillar 2.43

France, Italy, Spain, and the United Kingdom wrote a June 17, 2020, joint response letter, saying that “postponing our work (on digital taxation) and not addressing these challenges would constitute a collective failure.”44 In a June 18, 2020, statement, OECD Secretary-General José Ángel Gurría urged members of the inclusive framework to remain engaged in negotiations and meet the goal of delivering a global solution by the end of the year.45 However, it was clear that pillar 1 was already on the brink of collapse when the blueprints of both pillars were published in October 2020.46

This was disappointing for developing countries anticipating better revenue allocation. According to the OECD’s economic impact assessment published in October 2020, on average, low-, middle-, and high-income jurisdiction groups would all benefit from modest revenue gains (global revenue gain is projected to be 0.2 to 0.5 percent of global corporate income tax revenues).47 Investment hubs48 would significantly lose tax revenues under pillar 1.49

While it was estimated that pillar 2 would yield a significant increase in corporate income tax revenues (1.7 to 2.8 percent of global corporate tax revenues) across low-, middle-, and high-income jurisdictions, the revenue gain was estimated to be relatively larger among high-income jurisdictions because gains from the income inclusion rule were estimated to accrue to the jurisdiction of the MNE group’s ultimate parent, generally high-income jurisdictions.50 Without pillar 1, the revenue gains from the global tax deal will accrue to powerful OECD countries, as Yariv Brauner has insisted since the outset of BEPS 2.0 negotiation. It is therefore argued that the international ramifications of the designs of the two pillars should be jointly addressed within the framework of a single multilateral convention.51 Against this background, developing countries have sought their own ways to tax digital companies by proposing the creation of new taxing rights via the addition of article 12B of the U.N. model tax convention. This allows source jurisdictions to impose withholding taxes on the gross amount of payments to automated digital service enterprises.52

B. The Biden Administration: Pillar 2 Centric Proposal

The transition from the Trump administration to the Biden administration brought significant change in the prospects for consensus-making in the inclusive framework on the two-pillar solution. The Biden administration appointed Janet Yellen Treasury secretary and Itai Grinberg Treasury deputy assistant secretary for multilateral tax to assume the role of negotiators in the global tax deal.

Yellen withdrew Mnuchin’s safe harbor proposal in February 2021 and returned to the international negotiating table.53 Next, the United States shifted priority between pillar 1 and pillar 2 by presenting its plan on the two-pillar solution to the inclusive framework steering group on April 8, 2021.54 The U.S. plan put pillar 2 in the center of the global tax deal to end the race to the bottom over multinational corporate taxation.

Pillar 2 was useful in avoiding putting U.S. MNEs at a competitive disadvantage under the U.S. Made in America Tax Plan to increase corporate tax revenue by raising the statutory corporate tax rate to 28 percent and the GILTI effective tax rate to 21 percent.55 Pillar 1 is positioned to stabilize a multilateral international tax architecture to address the proliferation of unilateral measures.56 The United States proposed a simplification of pillar 1 because it was not expected that the complexities and wide scope of the pillar 1 blueprint would be approved by the Senate. The simplification plan limits the number of in-scope MNEs to no more than 100 without materially reducing the quantum of profits available for reallocation using quantitative criteria of revenues and profit margins.57

Although the Biden administration revived the hope of reaching a consensus on the global tax deal, it was not what inclusive framework member countries, except large powerful developed countries, expected. Developing countries were disappointed with the U.S. pillar-2-centric proposal.58 Eastern European countries, including Hungary and Poland, disliked the minimum tax because they used tax preferences to attract factories from Germany and France.59 Ireland announced that it no longer objected to pillar 2, but would never tolerate the minimum tax rate set above 12.5 percent.60

The United States, however, proposed on May 20, 2021, to the steering group of the inclusive framework that the global minimum tax rate should be at least 15 percent, notwithstanding the announcement of Ireland.61 The proposal was welcomed by Germany and France, which had been going to accept even 12.5 percent, but Eastern European countries and China62 were not happy about the rate being higher than their expectations.63 Developing countries were not satisfied with the proposal because they thought the 15 percent minimum rate was too low and feared that the revenue would go to the rich home jurisdictions of the MNEs.64 Also, developing countries were divided over the desirability of the influence of global minimum tax on their preferential tax regimes.65 As for pillar 1, developing countries required at least 20 percent of the deemed residual profit of MNEs to be reallocated to consumer countries to increase revenue.66

It is certain that the U.S. proposal in May paved the way for the G-7 agreement in June67 and the inclusive framework and G-20 meeting agreements in July,68 although the G-7 agreement was criticized for its minimum rate being too low and lacking consideration for developing countries.69 Following negotiations to determine concrete numbers, the G-20 agreement was finally reached in October 2021, confirming that the global minimum tax rate is 15 percent and amount A is 25 percent of the deemed residual profit.70 Ireland, which did not join the inclusive framework agreement in July, finally joined the G-20 agreement in October after careful deliberation to retain its headline corporate tax rate of 12.5 percent for companies outside the scope of pillar 2, while the 15 percent rate applies to in-scope MNEs.71

The pillar-2-centric global tax deal, accompanied by the reduced scope of pillar 1, was harshly criticized from the revenue allocation perspective.72 It is clear from this criticism that many jurisdictions, including investment hubs, Eastern European countries, and other developing countries, are dissatisfied with the revenue allocation pushed by the G-7 countries, home to large MNEs.

C. Source Jurisdictions Strike Back

1. QDMTT Late to the GLOBE Rules

The global tax deal story did not end with the 2021 agreement. The GLOBE model rules published in December 202173 surprised tax experts worldwide. The model rules contained a new tax instrument that had been only slightly discussed before74: the qualified domestic minimum top-up tax (QDMTT) in article 10.1 of the model rules.75 The QDMTT functions roughly as a domestic minimum tax that:

operates to increase domestic tax liability with respect to domestic Excess Profits to the Minimum Rate for the jurisdiction and Constituent Entities for a Fiscal Year.76

The QDMTT is a domestic tax but is excluded from the definition of covered tax77 in calculating jurisdictional ETR.78 Instead, a QDMTT is creditable against the IIR and the UTPR in calculating the amount of jurisdictional top-up tax.79 This means that the QDMTT has the highest priority in taxing excess profits in the GLOBE model rules. If jurisdictions introduce the QDMTT, they can soak up tax revenue from undertaxed excess profits ahead of the application of the IIR by the jurisdictions of ultimate parent entities (UPEs) and the UTPR in other jurisdictions. Therefore, the addition of the QDMTT has completely altered the rule order of pillar 2, and the QDMTT would greatly increase the revenue gains of source jurisdictions in pillar 2,80 in contrast to the previous criticism of pillar 2’s revenue allocation mechanism, which would mainly benefit residence jurisdictions.

The background of the addition of the QDMTT to the GLOBE model rules is a complete mystery for outsiders.81 As Michael Devereux and John Vella astutely point out, if it was discussed and agreed upon before, then it is odd that the QDMTT was not mentioned in the inclusive framework statement in October 2021.82 On the other hand, if an agreement on the QDMTT was not reached before October 2021, its addition significantly alters pillar 2’s incentives and distributional consequences.83 Considering the QDMTT’s significant revenue redistribution role to source jurisdictions,84 it is possible to speculate that the QDMTT was inserted because the majority of the inclusive framework member countries other than the G-7 countries requested it and the G-7 countries conceded to those countries under the uncertain U.S. political situation.85 If this speculation is true, the traditional problem that rich OECD countries are imposing standards that favor them in the name of inclusivity86 was partly overcome, at least on this point, even though it may be insufficient.87 Therefore, accusation of the unfairness of the global minimum tax without considering the effect of the QDMTT88 is too simplistic.

2. QDMTT Ordering Rules and CFC Rules

The effect of the QDMTT on the ordering rules in the GLOBE model rules extends not only to the application of the IIR but also to the application of the controlled foreign corporation tax regime.89 Under the model rules, covered tax includes the UPE jurisdiction’s CFC tax.90 The CFC tax is allocated to the constituent entity to calculate its ETR in the subsidiary’s jurisdiction.91 Therefore, a QDMTT applies a top-up tax on a post-CFC tax regime basis to increase the domestic tax liability on excess profits in the jurisdiction to the minimum rate. To determine the exact amount of a QDMTT, it is reasonable to interpret that the QDMTT is not creditable to CFC tax.92 If the QDMTT is creditable, a circular issue is created when calculating the jurisdictional ETR.93 Commentary to the GLOBE model rules published in March 2022 mentions “domestic tax regimes should not provide credit for any tax imposed under a Qualified UTPR or IIR” to avoid a circularity problem,94 but remains silent on the creditability of a QDMTT. Accordingly, Heydon Wardell-Burrus argues for the contrary interpretation — that a QDMTT is creditable to grant source jurisdictions priority over UPE jurisdictions.95 Brian Arnold also supports the idea that residence jurisdictions should grant foreign tax credit for source jurisdictions’ QDMTT.96

The argument that a residence jurisdiction should grant credit for a QDMTT in applying CFC rules is understandable considering the political situation of the United States at that time. The Biden administration failed to enact the Build Back Better Act, which included provisions to reform the GILTI regime into a qualified IIR at the end of 2021. If the GILTI regime is not updated to a qualified IIR, it is considered a “controlled foreign company tax regime” in the model rules, superseding the priority given to the United States,97 notwithstanding its broken promises.98

Wardell-Burrus is afraid of creating unintended incentives for countries to expand CFC rules if a QDMTT is not creditable.99 Also, he argues for the primacy of the QDMTT based on the formula for calculating the top-up tax amount in the model rules. The QDMTT is imposed on excess profits calculated by subtracting the substance-based income exclusion (SBIE) from net GLOBE income for the jurisdiction.100 According to Wardell-Burrus, it is odd that “country representatives bargained for the SBIE to be excluded from the top-up tax amount, only to have this benefit taken away through CFC rules which would give the relevant revenue to another jurisdiction.”101

Moreover, Arnold characterizes the QDMTT as:

a simpler and more certain method for countries to increase their domestic taxes on the excess profit of an MNE group to avoid giving up potential tax revenue to other countries.102

He justifies the priority of the QDMTT for source jurisdictions by the availability of nonqualified domestic minimum tax,103 which is categorized as covered tax, creditable against a CFC tax.104

The administrative guidance on the GLOBE model rules published in February officially used the QDMTT acronym for the qualified domestic minimum top-up tax and added an explanation of the ordering rule to the commentary of the model rules. This clarifies the priority of the QDMTT over the CFC rules, including the GILTI regime,105 by excluding a CFC tax from the calculation of the ETR for QDMTT purposes,106 with a lenient allocation mechanism regarding a blended CFC tax for regular GLOBE ETR calculation purposes to entice the United States to allow FTCs for a QDMTT.107

III. Pillar 2 Winners and Losers

A. Pillar 2 Implementation in Each Jurisdiction

Following the publication of the GLOBE model rules in December 2021, each jurisdiction started implementation into its domestic tax law.108 Early adopters were South Korea and Japan, although neither officially announced its stance on the introduction of a QDMTT.109 Several emerging Southeast Asian countries, including Malaysia, Thailand, and Vietnam, which are assumed to have tax incentives to attract foreign MNEs, will implement pillar 2 with a QDMTT in 2024.110 All EU member countries are required to enact the GLOBE rules by the end of 2023 following the EU directive on pillar 2 adopted by the EU Council in December 2022.111 The United Kingdom and Canada, which are the remaining G-7 countries except the United States, will implement pillar 2 with a QDMTT.

Investment hubs, including Singapore, Hong Kong, Ireland, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and Switzerland, will institute a QDMTT.112 Moreover, even the U.K. crown dependencies113 and Caribbean islands114 are moving forward to implement pillar 2 along with a QDMTT. On the other hand, countries in Latin America and Africa are late to implement pillar 2.115

The trend is for countries, except for a limited number of high-tax countries, such as Japan, to adopt pillar 2 along with a QDMTT to avoid other jurisdictions collecting taxes on excess profits in their jurisdictions.116

B. Revenue Estimates

Countries cannot be indifferent to the effect of pillar 2 on their tax revenue. According to the latest OECD economic impact assessment (in January), the estimated annual global revenue gains from pillar 2 amounted to $220 billion for 2018, while those from pillar 1 were estimated to be only $13 billion to $36 billion for 2021 or $12 billion to $25 billion per year on average over the period 2017-2021.117 However, official jurisdiction-level estimates are not yet available.

The EU Tax Observatory study group estimated the revenue effects of pillar 2 without ratifying pillar 1 for each jurisdiction.118 Its estimates are based on the OECD’s country-by-country report statistics. They indicate that global revenue gains are more modest (€139 billion to €165 billion) than the OECD estimates.119 As for the distribution of revenue gains among jurisdictions, most of the revenue gains accrued to investment hubs, including Bermuda, the Cayman Islands, Hong Kong, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Singapore, and Switzerland in its host country scenario, in which all jurisdictions are assumed to introduce a QDMTT.120 As the study group acknowledges, however, the estimates do not incorporate behavioral changes of either MNEs or jurisdictions in response to pillar 2, and they make a strong assumption that all jurisdictions introduce a QDMTT.121 Considering the potential for MNE behavioral changes, investment hubs might lose a fair amount of cash inflow and tax base.122 However, the global minimum tax rate of 15 percent is too low to make it happen.123

The U.S. Joint Committee on Taxation factored in behavioral changes of MNEs in estimating the revenue effect of pillar 2 on the United States.124 The JCT’s upper boundary projection is a $224.2 billion revenue increase for the United States during the 10-year budget window of 2023-2033, based on the assumption that in-scope U.S. MNEs shift up to 75 percent of their low-taxed profits to the United States, compared with the hypothetical baseline in which no jurisdiction has enacted or plans to enact pillar 2. The lower boundary projection is a revenue decrease of $174.5 billion during the 2023-2033 period, based on the assumption that up to 75 percent of the low-taxed profits are shifted to jurisdictions with a QDMTT.125 Because there will be significant heterogeneity in responses across U.S. MNEs, the JCT assumes a modified baseline between the upper and lower boundary scenarios.

In scenario 1 (the rest of the world126 enacts pillar 2 in 2025, but the United States does not), the revenue decrease is projected to be $122 billion during 2023-2033. On the other hand, in scenario 2, in which both the rest of the world and the United States enact pillar 2, the revenue decrease is projected to be $56.5 billion.127 In either scenario, the United States will lose revenue because it assumes that other jurisdictions’ QDMTTs will be credited against U.S. taxes, including the GILTI tax and the corporate alternative minimum tax on foreign income.128

U.S. revenue would increase if the rest of the world does not enact pillar 2, while the United States enacts it (the JCT’s scenarios 4 and 5), which Kimberly Clausing, who was the lead economist for the Office of Tax Analysis at the U.S. Treasury under the Biden administration in 2021-2022, thinks is realistic.129 But these scenarios are not realistic under the trend of widespread introduction of QDMTTs.130 From a theoretical perspective, the fact that the vast majority of the profits of in-scope MNEs with parents in the G-7 countries can be attributed to MNEs that also have a presence in other G-7 countries,131 and that G-7 countries other than the United States have already adopted or will adopt pillar 2, provides the rest of the world with a strong incentive to adopt a QDMTT.132

Although Clausing stresses that the estimates are heavily dependent on the assumptions of behavioral changes regarding profit shifting and that more low-taxed profits will shift to the United States,133 it is inevitable that the widespread introduction of QDMTTs will decrease U.S. tax revenue. A German estimate indicates that the host country’s increase in the ETR greatly offsets the tax revenue gains of the UPE jurisdictions from the reduction in profit shifting.134 The latest German revenue estimate expects that the annual revenue increase from pillar 2, including the revenue increase from the reduction in profit shifting, will be in the range of only €3.4 billion to €3.9 billion in 2026, which is equivalent to only 0.4 percent of the total annual tax revenue in 2021.135 Moreover, the report of the estimate states that the projected revenue increase from the QDMTT, with a range of €2 billion to €2.3 billion, is likely to be overestimated.136

C. Normative Analysis

1. The Primacy of QDMTT

Pillar 2’s promise for the global economy is that the GLOBE rules would set a floor for corporate tax competition, a goal that requires collective action to carry out.137 Through cooperation, an MNE’s home jurisdiction can introduce minimum taxes without the fear that only MNEs headquartered in its jurisdiction will suffer from a competitive disadvantage. The home jurisdiction also increases tax revenue if its MNEs’ profit shifting is curbed by the minimum tax. Once a floor is set, host jurisdictions no longer have to provide tax incentives to attract foreign MNEs, raising tax revenue to the minimum tax level.

It seems a win-win situation if the level of corporate income tax revenue is now suboptimal worldwide. Some commentators welcome the development of pillar 2 as an accomplishment of “the Single Tax Principle”138 or “full taxation”139 in the global tax regime. Regarding this development, MNEs’ home jurisdictions may see the benefit of pillar 2 as ensuring an equal competitive environment for their MNEs, even though pillar 2 itself does not lead to an immediate direct increase in their tax revenue.140

However, Leopoldo Parada convincingly points out the lack of a clear distributive rule in the concept of full taxation.141 Ruth Mason appropriately acknowledges that it is unrealistic to expect jurisdictions to pursue full taxation regardless of which country will receive tax revenue.142 In this regard, not only pillar 1 but also pillar 2 are revenue allocation mechanisms.143 From this perspective, both early proponents and opponents of the global minimum tax clearly envisioned that tax revenue from it is collected by MNEs’ home jurisdictions.144 Proponents then defend the imposition of the minimum tax by a home jurisdiction as following from its subsidiary taxing rights,145 or its respect for source jurisdictions’ taxing rights carried out through FTCs.146 Allison Christians and Laurens van Apeldoorn propose expansion of passthrough-type residence taxation paradoxically with carefully tailored FTCs to ensure source jurisdictions can impose source taxes without worrying about tax competition.147 However, it is unclear whether these proponents predicted the emergence of the QDMTT in the GLOBE model rules.

Moreover, Joachim Englisch and Johannes Becker go further, arguing that some of the excess returns subject to the minimum tax originate from valuable intellectual property created in the UPE jurisdictions. The UPE jurisdiction’s minimum taxation therefore reinforces the principle of value creation.148

Some prominent commentators defend the primacy of the QDMTT against the IIR and even against CFC taxes149 to protect source countries’ primary taxing rights.150 One of these commentators justifies the QDMTT as a tool for developing countries to help save legislative costs by providing a tax instrument for setting their jurisdictional ETRs at exactly 15 percent.151

2. Case Against the Primacy of the QDMTT

However, there are three reasons why the primacy of the QDMTT is not always defensible by the traditional dichotomy of source and residence.

First, the terminology of source is so loose that the jurisdiction categorized as source does not necessarily mean a source jurisdiction in a traditional sense in the discussion of international taxation.152 A source jurisdiction in the GLOBE context can be understood as just a jurisdiction other than the UPE jurisdiction in which MNEs’ income is booked. Even if commentators argue for the primacy of the QDMTT for the benefit of developing countries, it is highly likely that these countries cannot raise revenue from the QDMTT, the BEPS Monitoring Group and the South Centre contend.153 This is because their tax base is built on existing transfer pricing rules,154 which have numerous problems, including profit shifting.155 It sounds even hypocritical to argue for the primacy of the QDMTT for developing countries156 despite recognizing that the GLOBE model rules are intended to apply where profits are allocated based on the vague concept of source or value creation.157 The concepts’ indeterminacy has been criticized by many commentators.158 Accordingly, the plausible idea of expanding passthrough-type residence taxation as a backstop for source jurisdictions to increase source taxes without worrying about tax competition159 will not be achieved by the GLOBE rules.

Not only developing countries that host foreign MNEs but also investment hubs are included in source jurisdictions in the GLOBE context. Many of them, however, are rich jurisdictions with sufficient legislative and administrative capacity to tweak and implement their own domestic tax rules. The BEPS Monitoring Group persuasively points out that the QDMTT will benefit conduit jurisdictions that have adopted tax incentives to encourage MNEs to declare high profits there, but will not benefit most developing countries considering the low global minimum ETR of 15 percent compared with the world weighted average headline corporate tax rate of 25 percent.160 Moreover, despite that the QDMTT was invented for developing countries to help save legislative costs to raise the jurisdictional ETR to exactly 15 percent, there is still an argument that it may be difficult to implement in many developing countries.161 It is possible that only investment hubs, not developing countries in general, can enjoy tax revenue increases from QDMTT without losing foreign investment.162 Accordingly, QDMTT is not a good alternative tax instrument to pillar 1, even if its sudden insertion in the GLOBE model rules was implicitly intended to reallocate taxing rights on the excess returns of MNEs.

Second, the compliance costs of pillar 2 are borne by in-scope MNEs,163 including those that are not engaged in aggressive tax planning such as Japanese MNEs.164 In-scope MNEs are required to calculate ETR for QDMTT and other GLOBE rules separately because of the administrative guidance published in February, which aimed to calculate the amount of QDMTT before CFC tax. It is unclear how effectively the QDMTT safe harbor allowed in the administrative guidance published in July165 will alleviate the compliance burden of in-scope MNEs. It is unfair that these in-scope MNEs are forced to incur a heavy compliance burden for revenue increases in other countries.

Third, QDMTT should not be prioritized over CFC rules in certain cases. It is understandable that the U.S. GILTI regime, which the Biden administration failed to reform to a qualified IIR, should not be prioritized over the QDMTT.166 However, the CFC rules in many jurisdictions are anti-tax-avoidance measures to counter tax avoidance achieved by routing investments through low-tax jurisdictions.167 If the QDMTT in low-tax jurisdictions always trumps the CFC rules of residence jurisdictions, the tax base of the UPE jurisdictions is materially eroded168 by the global tax deal. This consequence contradicts the OECD’s traditional position that CFC rules are legitimate instruments to protect the domestic tax base and do not conflict with tax conventions.169 Further, after the adoption of the anti-tax-avoidance directive (ATAD) (2016/1164) in the EU, it is even possible to say that a CFC tax, at least as a supplement to transfer pricing rules,170 is now considered to be an essential element of the legislative arsenal used to combat tax avoidance in the OECD, the EU, and other related jurisdictions.171

IV. Consequence of International Cooperation

Ironically, pillar 2, originally purposed to address remaining BEPS issues, will result in keeping the profit-shifting incentive intact because of its low minimum rate. Moreover, pillar 2, as the second-best alternative to pillar 1 for reallocating taxing rights on the excess returns of MNEs, cannot achieve its goal because of its dependence on flawed transfer pricing rules. Instead, it provides rich low-tax investment hubs with a great opportunity to raise additional corporate tax revenue172 without losing their competitive tax environment. Investment hubs that attract substantial economic activities are unlikely to lose their competitive tax environment because of the SBIE173 and qualified refundable tax credits174 in the GLOBE model rules.

This is a good deal for investment hubs considering the economic effects of both pillars. Originally, it was even possible in their worst scenario that they would lose a lot of tax revenue from pillar 1,175 as well as their competitive tax advantage via a higher global minimum tax. After much twisting and turning of the negotiations, pillar 1 will go away thanks to the United States, and pillar 2 will increase these hubs’ tax revenue by curtailing tax competition without adding burdening costs,176 although they have long been the greatest beneficiaries of international tax competition, colluding with tax-aggressive MNEs. Is this a project worth pursuing globally, incurring significant negotiation, legislative, administrative, and compliance costs?

FOOTNOTES

1 OECD, “Statement on a Two-Pillar Solution to Address the Tax Challenges Arising From the Digitalisation of the Economy” (Oct. 8, 2021).

2 OECD, “Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digitalisation of the Economy — Policy Note” (Jan. 23, 2019).

3 According to the latest inclusive framework agreement on the implementation of pillar 1, a multilateral convention for pillar 1 requires at least 30 jurisdictions accounting for 60 percent of the ultimate parent entities (UPEs) of in-scope MNEs signing the multilateral convention before the end of 2023. See OECD, “Outcome Statement on the Two-Pillar Solution to Address the Tax Challenges Arising From the Digitalisation of the Economy” (July 11, 2023). This threshold implies the U.S. ratification is indispensable. See Quentin Parrinello et al., “The Long Road to Pillar One Implementation: Impact of Global Minimum Thresholds for Key Countries of the Effective Implementation of the Reform,” EU Tax Observatory Note (July 2023).

4 See infra Section III.A.

5 In this article, the concept of “excess returns” includes both “residual profits” in pillar 1 and “excess profits” in pillar 2. For the convoluted usage of these terms, see Lilian V. Faulhaber, “Lost in Translation: Excess Returns and the Search for Substantial Activities,” 25 Fla. Tax Rev. 545 (2022); Stephen E. Shay, “The Deceptive Allure of Taxing ‘Residual Profits,’” 75 Bull. for Int’l Tax’n 527 (2021).

6 For the longer-term development of the discussion on tax and digitalization in the OECD, see Richard Collier, “The Evolution of Thinking on Tax and the Digitalization of Business 1996-2018,” 15 World Tax J. 145 (2023).

7 OECD, “Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting,” 11 (2013).

8 Hugh Ault, “Some Reflections on the OECD and the Sources of International Tax Principles,” Tax Notes Int’l, June 17, 2013, p. 1195.

9 OECD, “Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digital Economy, Action 1 — 2015 Final Report,” at para. 383 (2015).

10 See id. at para. 364.

11 See id. at para. 385.

12 See id. at para. 383.

13 European Commission, “A Fair and Efficient Tax System in the European Union for the Digital Single Market,” COM(2017) 547 final (Sept. 21, 2017).

14 See id. at 9 (“New international rules specific to the challenges raised by digital economy are needed to determine where the value of businesses is created and how it should be attributed for tax purposes.”).

15 European Commission, “Proposal for a Council Directive Laying Down Rules Relating to the Corporate Taxation of a Significant Digital Presence,” COM(2018) 147 final (Mar. 21, 2018).

16 European Commission, “Proposal for a Council Directive on the Common System of a Digital Services Tax on Revenues Resulting From the Provision of Certain Digital Services,” COM(2018) 148 final (Mar. 21, 2018).

17 See Pascal Saint-Amans, Paradis Fiscaux: Comment on a Changé le Cours De L’Histoire 242 (2023) (in French).

18 See OECD, “Tax Challenges Arising From Digitalisation — Interim Report 2018: Inclusive Framework on BEPS,” paras. 388-394 (2018).

20 See Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 236.

21 The U.S. academia proposed a global minimum tax based on GILTI and BEAT. See, e.g., Itai Grinberg, “International Taxation in an Era of Digital Disruption: Analyzing the Current Debate,” 97 Taxes 73 (2019); G. Charles Beller, “GILTI: ‘Made in America’ for European Tax Unilateral Measures & Cooperative Surplus in the International Tax Competition Game,” 38 Va. Tax Rev. 271 (2019); Susan C. Morse, “GILTI: The Co-Operative Potential of a Unilateral Minimum Tax,” 2019 B.T.R. 512.

23 See Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 236.

24 See OECD, supra note 2.

25 See id.

26 OECD, “Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digitalisation of the Economy — Public Consultation Document” (Feb. 2019).

27 OECD, “Programme of Work to Develop a Consensus Solution to the Tax Challenges Arising From the Digitalisation of the Economy” (2019).

28 OECD, supra note 2, at 1. See also OECD, supra note 27, at para. 7.

29 Id. at para. 52.

30 Id. at para. 22.

31 John Vella, “Digital Services Taxes: Principle as a Double-Edged Sword,” 72 Nat’l Tax J. 821 (2019).

32 See Margarita Gelepithis and Martin Hearson, “The Politics of Taxing Multinational Firms in a Digital Age,” 29 J. Eur. Pub. Pol’y 708, 719-722 (2022).

33 Hearson, Rasmus Corlin Christensen, and Tovony Randriamanalina, “Developing Influence: The Power of ‘the Rest’ in Global Tax Governance,” 30 Rev. Int’l Pol. Econ. 841 (2022).

34 Yariv Brauner, “Developments on the Digital Economy Front: Progress or Regression?” 47 Intertax 422 (2019); Andres Baez Moreno and Brauner, “Taxing the Digital Economy Post BEPS . . . Seriously,” 58 Colum. J. Transnat’l L. 121, 183-186 (2019).

36 See id. at Annex 1, para. 15.

37 Id. at 8.

38 Id.

39 See Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 250.

40 See Stephanie Soong, “OECD’s Latest BEPS 2.0 Work a Positive Step, Irish Minister Says,” Tax Notes Int’l, Oct. 28, 2019, p. 368.

41 See letter from Mnuchin to OECD Secretary-General José Ángel Gurría (Dec. 3, 2019); Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 252; Soong, “U.S. Has ‘Serious Concerns’ About OECD Global Tax Overhaul Talks,” Tax Notes Int’l, Dec. 9, 2019, p. 937.

42 Brauner, “Lost in Construction: What Is the Direction of the Work on the Taxation of the Digital Economy?” 48 Intertax 270, 272 (2020).

43 See Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 263-264.

44 See Elodie Lamer and Sarah Paez, “U.S. Withdrawal From Digital Talks Marks ‘Collective Failure,’” Tax Notes Int’l, June 22, 2020, p. 1342.

45 See id.

46 OECD, “Tax Challenges Arising From Digitalisation — Report on Pillar One Blueprint” (2020); OECD, “Tax Challenges Arising From Digitalisation — Report on Pillar Two Blueprint” (2020) (OECD, pillar 2 blueprint).

47 See OECD, “Tax Challenges Arising From Digitalisation — Economic Impact Assessment,” at 15 and 61 (2020).

48 An investment hub is defined as a jurisdiction with a total inward foreign direct investment position above 150 percent of GDP. See id. at 26. For example, Ireland, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands are included.

49 See id. at 61-62.

50 See id. at 15 and 18.

51 See Pasquale Pistone and Alessandro Turina, “The Way Ahead: Policy Consistency and Sustainability of the GLoBE Proposal,” in Global Minimum Taxation?: An Analysis of the Global Anti-Base Erosion Initiative 415, 421 (2021).

52 Ryan Finley, “U.N. Committee Members Issue Independent Digital Taxation Proposal,” Tax Notes Int’l, Aug. 10, 2020, p. 801; Finley, “U.N. Releases Proposed Treaty Article on Digital Services Taxes,” Tax Notes Int’l, Oct. 19, 2020, p. 432.

53 See Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 273.

55 U.S. Department of the Treasury, “The Made in America Tax Plan” (Apr. 2021).

56 See supra note 54.

57 See id. The U.S. simplification plan presumably originated from Grinberg. See Grinberg, “Design of Scope Limitations for OECD Pillar 1 Work,” Tax Notes Int’l, June 15, 2020, p. 1221.

58 See Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 278.

59 See id.

60 See id. See also Soong and Kiarra M. Strocko, “Global Tax Reform Deal Must Respect Irish Rate, Donohoe Says,” Tax Notes Int’l, Apr. 26, 2021, p. 521.

61 U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Readout: U.S. Department of the Treasury’s Office of Tax Policy Meetings” (May 20, 2021).

62 On China’s position, see generally Wei Cui, “What Does China Want From International Tax Reform?Tax Notes Int’l, July 12, 2021, p. 141.

63 See Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 281.

64 See id. at 282.

65 See id. at 282-283.

66 See id. at 282.

67 G-7 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors Communiqué (June 5, 2021).

68 OECD, “Statement on a Two-Pillar Solution to Address the Tax Challenges Arising From the Digitalisation of the Economy” (July 1, 2021); OECD, “OECD Secretary-General Tax Report to G20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors” (July 2021).

69 See Saint-Amans, supra note 17, at 288. See also Brauner, “The Return of the Phoenix? The G-7 Countries’ Agreement on a 15 Percent Minimum Tax,” 49 Intertax 750 (2021).

70 See OECD, supra note 1.

71 See Soong, “Donohoe Weighs Pros and Cons of Ireland Joining OECD Tax Deal,” Tax Notes Int’l, Sept. 27, 2021, p. 1759; Soong, “Final OECD Global Tax Deal Text Addresses Ireland’s Concerns,” Tax Notes Int’l, Oct. 11, 2021, p. 221; Soong and Paez, “Ireland, Estonia to Join OECD Global Tax Reform Deal,” Tax Notes Int’l, Oct. 11, 2021, p. 222.

72 Brauner, “Agreement? What Agreement? The 8 October 2021, OECD Statement in Perspective,” 50 Intertax 2 (2022).

73 OECD, “Tax Challenges Arising From the Digitalisation of the Economy — Global Anti-Base Erosion Model Rules (Pillar Two)” (2021).

74 See OECD, pillar 2 blueprint, supra note 46, at para. 491 (“Jurisdictions that wish to ensure that they can apply the UTPR in every year could ensure the jurisdictional ETR of every MNE operating in their jurisdictions is at least at the agreed minimum rate by introducing an annual domestic minimum tax on income with the same tax base and tax rate as the GloBE rules.”). See also Mindy Herzfeld, “How Does the Qualified Domestic Minimum Top-Up Tax Fit Into Pillar 2?Tax Notes Int’l, Apr. 18, 2022, p. 315. The first academic works that argue for the introduction of a conditional domestic minimum tax to defend primary taxing rights of source jurisdictions are Noam Noked’s works. See Noked, “Defense of Primary Taxing Rights,” 40 Va. Tax Rev. 341 (2021); Noked, “Potential Response to GLOBE: Domestic Minimum Taxes in Countries Affected by the Global Minimum Tax,” Tax Notes Int’l, May 17, 2021, p. 943.

75 OECD, supra note 73, at 64. That the GLOBE model rules themselves did not name the acronym for qualified domestic minimum top-up tax implies QDMTT was an afterthought or late arrival. See Herzfeld, supra note 74, at 316.

76 OECD, GLOBE model rules, art. 10.1.

77 OECD, GLOBE model rules, art. 4.2.2.(b).

78 OECD, GLOBE model rules, art. 5.1.1.

79 OECD, GLOBE model rules, art. 5.2.3.

80 See Michael Devereux et al., “Pillar 2: Rule Order, Incentives, and Tax Competition,” Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation Policy Brief 2022 (Jan. 14, 2022).

81 We cannot find any single reference to the QDMTT in Saint-Amans, supra note 17. On the opacity of the OECD policymaking process, see Allison Christians and Laurens van Apeldoorn, “The OECD Inclusive Framework,” 72 Bull. Int’l Tax’n 226 (2018).

82 See Devereux and Vella, “The Impact of the Global Minimum Tax on Tax Competition,” 15 World Tax J. 323, 335 (2023).

83 See id.

84 Christians, “Let the GILTI/GLOBE Games Begin,” Tax Notes Int’l, May 16, 2022, p. 913.

85 Some commentators connote this type of bargaining. See Heydon Wardell-Burrus, “Should CFC Regimes Grant a Tax Credit for Qualified Domestic Minimum Top-Up Taxes?Tax Notes Int’l, June 27, 2022, p. 1649 (Wardell-Burrus, “CFC Regimes”) (“It seems plausible that at least some jurisdictions may have agreed to the GLOBE rules on the assumption that they could avoid the application of top-up taxes to profits sourced within their borders by adopting a QDMTT.”); Wardell-Burrus, “Pillar Two and Developing Countries: The STTR and GloBE Implementation,” 51 Intertax 118, 127 (2023) (Wardell-Burrus, “Developing Countries”) (“Ultimately, the aim is to ensure that developing countries can impose the minimum tax permitted under the GloBE Rules without ceding the revenue to another jurisdiction.”); Biden’s Global Tax Surrender Harms American Workers and Our Economy: Hearing Before the House Ways and Means Committee Subcommittee on Tax (2023) (statement of Mindy Herzfeld, professor, University of Florida).

86 See Brauner, “Serenity Now! The (Not So) Inclusive Framework and the Multilateral Instrument,” 25 Fla. Tax Rev. 489, 529-533 (2022). See also Tsilly Dagan, International Tax Policy: Between Competition and Cooperation 133-134 (2018).

87 See Cees Peters, “The Legitimacy of the OECD’s Work on Pillar Two: An Analysis of the Overconfidence in a ‘Devilish Logic,’” 51 Intertax 554 (2023) (criticizing the lack of technical and political accountability of the OECD in the pillar 2 project); see Dagan, “GloBE: The Potential Costs of Cooperation,” 51 Intertax 638 (2023).

88 See, e.g., Rita de la Feria, “The Perceived (Un)Fairness of the Global Minimum Corporate Tax Rate,” in The Pillar 2 Global Minimum Tax (forthcoming); Assaf Harpaz, “International Tax Reform: Who Gets a Seat at the Table?” 44 U. Pa. J. Int’l L. 1007 (2023).

89 See Herzfeld, “More on GLOBE Ordering: CFC Rules,” Tax Notes Int’l, May 2, 2022, p. 603.

90 OECD, GLOBE model rules, art. 4.2.1.(a).

91 OECD, GLOBE model rules, art. 4.3.2.(c).

92 See Wardell-Burrus, “CFC Regimes,” supra note 85, at 1654.

93 See Herzfeld, supra note 89, at 606; Wardell-Burrus, “CFC Regimes,” supra note 85, at 1652-1653.

94 OECD, “Tax Challenges Arising From the Digitalisation of the Economy — Commentary to the Global Anti-Base Erosion Model Rules (Pillar Two),” at art. 4, para. 45 (2022).

95 See Wardell-Burrus, “CFC Regimes,” supra note 85, at 1654; Wardell-Burrus, “Developing Countries,” supra 85, at 127-129.

96 Brian J. Arnold, “An Investigation Into the Interaction of CFC Rules and the OECD Pillar Two Global Minimum Tax,” 76 Bull. Int’l Tax’n 270, 286-288 (2022).

97 See Herzfeld, supra note 89, at 603.

98 See Herzfeld, “How to Think About How the US Congress Thinks About International Tax Reforms,” 2022 B.T.R. 550.

99 See Wardell-Burrus, “CFC Regimes,” supra note 85, at 1654.

100 OECD, GLOBE model rules, art. 5.2.2.

101 See Wardell-Burrus, “Developing Countries,” supra note 85, at 128.

102 See Arnold, supra note 96, at 282.

103 A commentator points out the possibility of countries adopting a non-qualified domestic minimum top-up tax, which is characterized as covered taxes, because covered taxes would have priority over other countries’ CFC rules. See Noked, “Designing Domestic Minimum Taxes in Response to the Global Minimum Tax,” 50 Intertax 678, 684-685 (2022).

104 See Arnold, supra note 96, at 287.

105 The inclusive framework has agreed that the U.S. GILTI regime meets the definition of a CFC tax regime under the GLOBE rules and must be treated as such. See OECD, “Tax Challenges Arising From the Digitalisation of the Economy — Administrative Guidance on the Global Anti-Base Erosion Model Rules (Pillar Two),” 67 (Feb. 2023).

106 See id. at 106.

107 See id. at 67-70. See also Wardell-Burrus, “GloBE Administrative Guidance — The QDMTT and GILTI Allocation,” SSRN (Feb. 17, 2023).

108 Soong, “Asia Leaps Ahead on Adopting OECD Global Minimum Tax Rules,” Tax Notes Int’l, Feb. 27, 2023, p. 1110; Herzfeld, “A Pillar 2 Tour Around the World,” Tax Notes Int’l, Apr. 17, 2023, p. 305 (Herzfeld, “Tour”); Herzfeld, “Cruising the World With Pillar 2,” Tax Notes Int’l, Aug. 28, 2023, p. 1053.

109 Soong, supra note 108, at 1111-1112; Herzfeld, “Tour,” supra note 108, at 305-306. Japan will likely introduce a UTPR and a QDMTT in the 2024 tax reform. See Jiyuu Minshu-tou and Koumei-tou, Reiwa 5 nendo Zeisei Kaisei Taikou, at 8 (Dec. 16, 2022) (in Japanese). However, the ETR in Japan is seldom likely to be below 15 percent because its statutory tax rate is approximately 30 percent, and the ceiling for nonrefundable research and development tax credits, which are the largest tax expenditures for businesses, is half of corporate tax liability before the credits.

110 See Soong, supra note 108, at 1113; Herzfeld, “Tour,” supra note 108, at 306; Soong, “Vietnam Proposes Global Minimum Tax Rules to Apply in 2024,” Tax Notes Int’l, July 31, 2023, p. 618.

111 Council Directive (EU) 2022/2523 of 14 December 2022 on ensuring a global minimum level of taxation for multinational enterprise groups and large-scale domestic groups in the Union.

112 See Herzfeld, “Tour,” supra note 108, at 307-308; Soong, “Luxembourg Government Approves Global Minimum Tax Bill,” Tax Notes Today Int’l, Aug. 1, 2023.

113 Soong, “Crown Dependencies to Adopt OECD Pillar 2 Tax Rules for 2025,” Tax Notes Int’l, May 29, 2023, p. 1251.

114 Soong, “Bahamas Sets Out Potential Corporate Tax Responses to Pillar 2,” Tax Notes Int’l, May 29, 2023, p. 1235. Bermuda is going to introduce corporate tax but decided not to adopt a QDMTT for now. See Soong, “Bermuda Ponders Corporate Tax Regime in Line With Pillar 2,” Tax Notes Int’l, Aug. 14, 2023, p. 864.

115 See Herzfeld, “Tour,” supra note 108, at 309-310.

116 See id. at 310.

117 OECD, “Economic Impact Assessment of the Two-Pillar Solution Revenue Estimates for Pillar One & Pillar Two” (Jan. 18, 2023). IMF shows similar estimates that the annual net revenue increase from pillar 1 is $12 billion and a significant portion of the excess profits is reallocated from investment hubs to other countries. See IMF, International Corporate Tax Reform 12-13 (Feb. 2023).

118 Mona Baraké et al., “Revenue Effects of the Global Minimum Tax Under Pillar Two,” 50 Intertax 689 (2022).

119 See id. at 690.

120 See id. at 697-700.

121 See id. at 700. Felix Reitz, “Revenue Effects of the OECD Corporate Tax Reform — An Updated Impact Assessment of Pillar Two,” IFF-HSG Working Paper No. 2023-17 (July 2023) (showing similar results without incorporating MNEs’ behavioral responses).

122 See IMF, supra note 117, at 15-16.

123 See Amanda Athanasiou, “Global Minimum Tax Expected to Increase Revenues in Ireland,” Tax Notes Int’l, June 20, 2022, p. 1573 (citing an interview with an Irish professor, “Frank Barry of Trinity College Dublin said that fortunately, the difference between Ireland’s 12.5 percent corporate tax rate and a 15 percent minimum rate is sufficiently low that it’s unlikely to drive any U.S. companies out of the country.”).

125 See id. at 7.

126 “Rest of the world” means jurisdictions other than pillar 2 compliant jurisdictions: Canada, Japan, Liechtenstein, South Korea, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, Germany, Ireland, the Netherlands, and Sweden. See id. at 11-13. A lot of jurisdictions, including those in Southeast Asia and small islands, are going to implement pillar 2. See supra Section III.A.

127 See JCT, supra note 124, at 10.

128 See id. at 6.

129 See Kimberly A. Clausing, “The Revenue Consequences of Pillar 2: Five Key Considerations,” Tax Notes Int’l, July 24, 2023, p. 359.

130 See supra Section III.A.

131 Devereux, “International Tax Competition and Coordination With a Global Minimum Tax,” 76 Nat’l Tax J. 145, 158-159 (2023).

132 See id. at 160. The strong endorsement from the G-7 might have sent a reliable signal that the G-7 countries, except the United States, will implement an IIR, which will encourage other countries to introduce a QDMTT without credible legislation movement for a UTPR. On the incentive compatibility of pillar 2, see Cui, “Strategic Incentives for Pillar Two Adoption,” available at SSRN (Aug. 13, 2023).

133 Clausing, supra note 129, at 362.

134 See David Gstrein et al., Fiskalische Auswirkungen der Säule 1 (teilweise Neuverteilung von Besteuerungsrechten) und der Säule 2 (globale effektive Mindest-besteuerung) 17-19 (2023) (in German).

135 See id. at 21-22.

136 See id. at 21.

137 See, e.g., Clausing, supra note 129, at 360-361; Beller, supra note 21, at 306-312; Carlo Garbarino, “The Architecture of the Country-by-Country Minimum Tax Regime Proposed by the United States,” 25 Fla. Tax Rev. 835, 864-865 (2022).

138 Reuven Avi-Yonah and Young Ran (Christine) Kim, “Tax Harmony: Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax,” 43 Mich. J. Int’l L. 505, 508 (2022); Wolfgang Schön, “Is There Finally an International Tax System?” 13 World Tax J. 357, 375 (2021).

139 Ruth Mason, “The Transformation of International Tax,” 114 Am. J. Int’l L. 353 (2020).

140 Delegates from the Japanese Ministry of Finance imply this understanding. See Kenichi Nishikata et al., Kokusaikazei wo Meguru Genjou to Kadai, in Dai 74 kai Sozeikenkyutaikaikiroku at 138, 143, 166 (2022) (in Japanese). Achieving an equal competitive tax environment may seem beneficial for Japanese MNEs, most of which are not engaged in aggressive tax planning. However, it is unclear whether this is true. MNEs will be inevitably engaged in complicated tax planning to achieve a jurisdictional ETR of exactly 15 percent and maximize the SBIE amount under the GLOBE rules. See Wardell-Burrus, “Tax Planning Under the GloBE Rules,” 2022 B.T.R. 623.

Cui even shows a cynical view, with which I agree, that “delegates from many of the participating countries in the OECD’s Inclusive Framework were inclined to behave cooperatively, instead of focusing exclusively on national self-interests” because many delegates are from finance ministries and tax administrations and the success of the cooperative project indirectly lends legitimacy to future domestic tax increases. See Cui, supra note 132.

141 See Parada, “Full Taxation: The Single Tax Emperor’s New Clothes,” 24 Fla. Tax Rev. 729, 749-752 (2021).

142 See Mason, supra note 139, at 401 (“It was unrealistic to think that the states could pursue full taxation while remaining indifferent to which state received the tax. This Article thus argues that one of the most important — if underappreciated — outcomes of BEPS is that by increasing the salience of distributive issues and creating an inclusive forum for negotiating distributive outcomes, BEPS made it more, not less, likely that states would seriously reconsider longstanding distributive questions.”).

143 See Cui, “New Puzzles in International Tax Agreements,” 75 Tax L. Rev. 201, 233 (2022) (“How can countries be so keen to claim additional taxing rights (or be so sensitive to ceding tax rights to others) under Pillar One, but at the same time be willing to merely follow a set of allocation conventions under Pillar Two, regardless of their distributional consequences?”).

144 Avi-Yonah, “Hanging Together: A Multilateral Approach to Taxing Multinationals,” 5 Mich. Bus. & Entrepreneurial L. Rev. 137, 151 (2016) (“Capital exporting countries could obtain revenues from their MNEs without concerns about harming their competitiveness or MNEs migrating to other OECD countries.”). See Brauner’s consecutive works cited in supra Section II. Avi-Yonah, however, supports pillar 2 even if the United States loses revenue, because he believes “the US corporate tax was never primarily about raising revenue,” but “the main rationale for the corporate tax is to impose tax on rich shareholders to reduce inequality and to regulate large corporations.” See Avi-Yonah, “What Does the US Get From Pillar 2?” available at SSRN (Mar. 15, 2023).

145 See Joachim Englisch and Johannes Becker, “International Effective Minimum Taxation; The GLOBE Proposal,” 11 World Tax J. 483, 494 (2019).

146 See Morse, supra note 21, at 519; Avi-Yonah and Kim, supra note 138, at 549.

147 See Christians and van Apeldoorn, Tax Cooperation in an Unjust World 93-102 (2021).

148 See Englisch and Becker, supra note 145, at 494. See also Harry Grubert and Rosanne Altshuler, “Fixing the System: An Analysis of Alternative Proposals for the Reform of International Tax,” 66 Nat’l Tax J. 671, 675 (2013) (“It should be noted that designing a set of international tax rules is mainly a question of determining how excess returns attributable to U.S. developed intellectual property are taxed.”).

149 See supra Section II.C.2.

150 See Arnold, “The Ordering of Residence and Source Country Taxes and the OECD Pillar Two Global Minimum Tax,” 76 Bull. Int’l Tax’n 218, 224-225 (2022); Arnold, supra note 96, at 287; Wardell-Burrus, “CFC Regimes,” supra note 85, at 1654; Wardell-Burrus, “Developing Countries,” supra note 85, at 127-128; Christians et al., A Guide for Developing Countries on How to Understand and Adapt to the Global Minimum Tax 6-8 (Apr. 2023).

151 See Arnold, “Ordering,” supra note 150, at 224.

152 For example, the terminology of “source” states is often used to mean less affluent states and is distinguished from “intermediary” states. See Christians and van Apeldoorn, supra note 147, at 91, 112.

153 BEPS Monitoring Group, “Taxing Multinationals: The BEPS Proposals and Alternatives,” 6-7 (2023); Emmanuel Eze et al., “The GloBE Rules: Challenges for Developing Countries and Smart Policy Options to Protect Their Tax Base,” Tax Cooperation Policy Brief No. 35, at 2 (Aug. 18, 2023).

154 See OECD, GLOBE model rules, art. 3.2.3.

155 See Noked, “The Case for Domestic Minimum Taxes on Multinationals,” Tax Notes Int’l, Feb. 7, 2022, p. 667, at 672. See also Joseph L. Andrus and Collier, “Transfer Pricing and the Arm’s-Length Principle After the Pillars,” Tax Notes Int’l, Jan. 31, 2022, p. 543, at 554-555 (“A pillar 2-only approach would also do nothing to ameliorate the operational problems of the arm’s-length principle.”).

156 See supra note 85 and accompanying text.

157 Wardell-Burrus, “GILTI and the GloBE,” Oxford Center for Business Taxation WP23/1, at 47 (Feb. 2023).

158 See, e.g., Morse, “Value Creation: As Standard in Search of a Process,” 72 Bull. Int’l Tax’n 196 (2018); Johanna Hey, “‘Taxation Where Value Is Created’ and the OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Initiative,” 72 Bull. Int’l Tax’n 203 (2018). For the difficulty of determining the geographical “source” of income, see Ault and David F. Bradford, “Taxing International Income: An Analysis of the US System and Its Economic Premises” in Taxation in the Global Economy 11 (1990).

159 See supra note 147 and accompanying text.

160 BEPS Monitoring Group, supra note 153, at 6-7.

161 See Luis Eduardo Schoueri and Bruno Cesar Fettermann Nougueira dos Santos, “Effective Tax Rate Criteria and Source Taxation Under the OECD’s Pillar Two Proposals,” 77 Bull. Int’l Tax’n 386, 389 (2023). But see Afton Titus, “Pillar Two and African Countries: What Should Their Response Be? The Case for a Regional One,” 50 Intertax 711, 717 (2022) (“The benefits of introducing a QDMTT seem to outweigh the possible administrative burden that would come with its introduction.”).

162 See Parada, “Tailoring Developing Country Advice: A Response to Noam Noked,” Tax Notes Int’l, Feb. 14, 2022, p. 783.

163 Policymakers of home jurisdictions should not underestimate the burden of compliance costs that in-scope MNEs will incur in evaluating the economic impact to the national economy. See, e.g., Bundesministeriums der Finanzen, Entwurf eines Gesetzes für die Umsetzung der Richtlinie zur Gewähr-leistung einer globalen Mindestbesteuerung für multinationale Unter-nehmensgruppen und große inländische Gruppen in der Union und die Umsetzung weiterer Begleitmaßnahmen, at 3 and 105 (July 7, 2023) (in German) (German ministry of finance estimates that the German in-scope MNEs will incur an annual compliance cost of €40.6 million and one-time compliance cost of €322.6 million to comply with the GLOBE rules).

164 One of the biggest concerns for the Japanese in-scope MNEs regarding the two-pillar solution is not the increase of tax burden but the increase of compliance costs. See Mari Takahashi, “Japan’s Study on International Taxation in the Digital Economy: Fairness in Taxation, Trade and Competition,” 29 Int’l Transfer Pricing J. 120, 122 (2022) (introducing the report on international taxation by a study group established by Japan’s Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry).

165 OECD, “Tax Challenges Arising From the Digitalisation of the Economy — Administrative Guidance on the Global Anti-Base Erosion Model Rules (Pillar Two),” 77-79 (July 2023).

166 See supra notes 97 and 98 and accompanying text.

167 See Richard Krever, “Controlled Foreign Company Legislation: General Report” in Controlled Foreign Company Legislation 3, 3 (2020).

168 See Dieter Bettens, “The CFC Rule Under GloBE: Definition, Rule Order and Strategic Responses,” available at SSRN, at 34-36 (Dec. 2022). Arnold, however, says the CFC rules are generally prophylactic and are not intended to raise substantial revenue. See Arnold, supra note 96, at 287 n.103.

169 Commentary on article 1, para. 81 of the 2017 OECD model tax convention (the CFC rules “are now internationally recognised as a legitimate instrument to protect the domestic tax base”).

170 Even skeptics of the CFC rules in the ATAD would not deny the function of CFC tax as a supplement of the transfer pricing rules. See Alexander Rust, “Controlled Foreign Company Rule (Article 7 and 8 ATAD)” in A Guide to the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive 174, 193 (2020).

171 Krever, supra note 167, at 13. See also Christiana HJI Panayi, “The ATAD’s CFC Rule and Its Impact on the Existing Regimes of EU Member States” in The Implementation of Anti-BEPS Rules in the EU: A Comprehensive Study (2018) (finding the normative shift arising from the ATAD’s imposing CFC enactment rules on EU member states).

172 See, e.g., Paez, “Switzerland Expects CHF 1.6 Billion From First Year of Pillar 2,” Tax Notes Int’l, Aug. 28, 2023, p. 1158.

173 See Englisch, “GloBE Rules and Tax Competition,” 50 Intertax 859, 865 (2022); Faulhaber, “Pillar Two’s Built-In Escape Hatch,” 76 Nat’l Tax J. 167 (2023).

174 Several Western countries, including Ireland and the United Kingdom, have already been equipped with refundable R&D credits. See OECD, R&D Tax Incentives Database (2022 ed.), 26 (June 15, 2023). See also Christoph Spengel et al., “R&D Tax Incentive Regimes: A Comparison and Evaluation of Current Country Practice,” 14 World Tax J. 331, 338-341 (2022); Victoria Perry, “Pillar 2, Tax Competition, and Low Income Sub-Saharan African Countries,” 51 Intertax 105, 110 (2023) (“The goal apparently is to protect the impact of certain existing incentives (largely in developed countries) particularly, but not limited to, research and development credits.”). Belgium is going to amend its R&D tax credits to comply with the qualified refundable tax credits definition. See Pieter-Jan Wouters, “Belgian R&D Tax Credit to Be Aligned With Pillar Two and US GILTI Rules,” 63 Eur. Tax’n 344 (2023).

175 See supra note 49 and accompanying text.

176 See Ivan O. Ozai, “Tax Competition and the Ethics of Burden Sharing,” 42 Fordham Int’l L.J. 61, 78-80 (2018).

END FOOTNOTES

Copy RID